In a World of Trade Tensions,
What Do Tariffs Really Do?
WTO/11 April 2025 (Blog by Ralph Ossa, Ch.
Economist)
Trade
policy tensions are escalating fast. In recent months, several large economies have
announced or implemented sweeping new tariffs, reviving a policy tool that many
thought to have been largely relegated to the past. These developments have sparked
a flurry of political commentary – but behind the headlines, there exists a body
of economic research that helps to make sense of what tariffs actually do.
At
their core, tariffs are simple: they raise the domestic price of imported goods.
But their effects ripple through the economy in complex ways – altering prices,
wages, exchange rates and trade patterns. As governments revisit this powerful lever,
understanding the economic mechanisms at play has never been more important.
At
the most basic level, a tariff is a tax on imported products. It drives a wedge
between the world price and the domestic price. For instance, if a 10 per cent tariff
is imposed on a product with a world price of US$ 100, the domestic price becomes
US$ 110. The difference – US$ 10 – is collected as tariff revenue, which the government
can use to finance its expenditures.
Tariffs
can also affect the world price of a product, particularly when they are imposed
by a large economy. The logic is that higher domestic prices reduce domestic demand,
which in turn lowers world demand, and thus world prices. In our example, the world
price might fall to $95 after the tariff is imposed, resulting in a domestic price
of $104.50. In this case, part of the tariff is effectively paid by foreign producers.
This
cost-shifting creates incentives for large economies to unilaterally impose tariffs.
However, this so-called optimal tariff argument overlooks the possibility of retaliation.
If country A imposes tariffs on country B, country B has an incentive to respond
in kind. The end result is a trade war that leaves both sides worse off.
This
logic underpins the leading theory of trade negotiations. If all economies attempt
to benefit at each other’s expense, everyone ends up worse off – and this creates
incentives for cooperative trade policymaking. The economics literature on trade
policy has shown that the core WTO principles of reciprocity and non-discrimination
are effective tools for escaping the logic of mutually harmful tariffs (Bagwell
and Staiger, 2002).
The
extent to which tariffs pass through to consumer prices is ultimately an empirical
question. Evidence from the initial wave of US tariffs on China suggests full pass-through
to US consumers (Amiti et al. 2019; Fajgelbaum et al. 2019). However, these studies focus on short-term
effects and use methodologies that cannot fully account for broader macroeconomic
adjustments. Standard quantitative trade models typically predict at least some
cost-shifting to foreign producers.
A
broader question is how tariffs affect inflation. When a country imposes a tariff,
it causes a one-off increase in the domestic price level, but this does not necessarily
translate into sustained inflation. One channel through which a tariff could lead
to persistent inflation is a wage–price spiral, which is similar to what can happen
with other supply shocks.
Tariffs
do not just affect imports – they also affect exports. One direct channel is through
higher prices for intermediate goods, which undermine the competitiveness of exporting
firms; but broader general equilibrium effects are also important. Tariffs allow
import-competing sectors to expand, which draws resources – such as labour, capital
and land – away from other sectors, including exporting sectors.
This
process operates through changes in the real exchange rate, which measures domestic
prices relative to foreign prices, adjusted for the nominal exchange rate. As import-competing
sectors expand, they demand more workers, which pushes up wages across the economy.
Higher wages raise production costs for exporting firms, making them less competitive
in international markets. The result is an appreciation of the real exchange rate,
which makes exports relatively more expensive abroad.
A
related question is what happens to the nominal exchange rate. One channel is direct:
tariffs reduce import demand, and hence the demand for foreign currency, leading
to an appreciation of the domestic currency. Another channel is indirect: tariffs
may lead markets to anticipate tighter monetary policy to counter inflation, which
can also cause the domestic currency to appreciate. For trade effects, what ultimately
matters is the change in the real exchange rate; whether
this occurs through adjustments in wages, domestic prices, or the nominal exchange
rate is of secondary importance.
There
is, thus, a trade-off between the inflationary and competitiveness effects of tariffs.
If the exchange rate appreciates strongly, domestic prices rise little, but competitiveness
suffers significantly. If it appreciates only slightly, domestic prices rise more,
but competitiveness is less affected. Either way, tariffs impose economic costs.
A
topical question is whether tariffs affect trade imbalances. The answer depends
on whether one considers aggregate, bilateral or sectoral imbalances. Aggregate
trade imbalances reflect the gap between national saving and national investment
– a basic accounting identity. The logic is analogous to household finance: if a
household (country) saves, it must earn (export) more than it spends (imports).
To
improve the aggregate trade balance, tariffs would need to increase national saving
or reduce investment, which is a possibility. For instance, households might delay
consumption if they expect tariffs to be temporary, thereby raising saving. Alternatively,
tariffs could reduce investment by increasing the cost of capital goods, or by creating
policy uncertainty, leading firms to postpone spending.
However,
most economists expect tariffs to have only limited effects on aggregate imbalances.
Macroeconomic fundamentals – such as fiscal policy or the household savings rate
– play a more dominant role. This view is supported by empirical studies that have
found little impact of tariffs on aggregate trade balances so far (Furceri et al. 2022).
Tariffs
can, however, affect bilateral trade balances by altering relative prices. It is
entirely possible for country A to run a deficit with country B, B with C, and C
with A – without any of them having an aggregate trade imbalance.
Tariffs
can also affect sectoral trade balances. For example, higher tariffs on goods imports
tend to improve the goods trade balance by discouraging imports through higher domestic
prices, while worsening the services trade balance by reducing services exports
through an appreciation of the real exchange rate.
As
tariffs return to the trade policy agenda, it is worth recalling what economics
has long understood: tariffs are not just a tool for raising revenue or protecting
domestic industries – they are a policy lever with wide-ranging, and often unintended,
consequences. Their appeal in the short term can obscure longer-term costs to inflation,
competitiveness and international cooperation. In a world of growing trade tensions,
a clear-eyed view of those trade-offs is more important than ever.